http://www.citylab.com/commute/2015/01/why-cant-public-transit-be-free/384950/
By Joe Pinsker, January 29, 2015

About 500 subway riders in Stockholm have an ingenious
scheme to avoid paying fares. The group calls itself Planka.nu (rough
translation: "dodge the fare now"), and they've banded together because
getting caught free-riding comes with a steep $120 penalty. Here's how
it works: Each member pays about $12 in monthly dues—which beats paying
for a $35 weekly pass—and the resulting pool of cash more than covers any fines members incur.
As an informal insurance group, Planka.nu has proven both successful
and financially solvent. "We could build a Berlin Wall in the metro
stations," a spokesperson for Stockholm's public-transit system told The New York Times. "They would still try to find ways to dodge."
These Swedes' strategy might seem like classic
corner-cutting, but there's a dreamy political tint to their actions.
Like similar groups before them—Paris's Métro-cheating "fraudster mutuals,"
for example—they argue that public transportation should be free, just
like education, parks, and libraries (and health care, in some parts of
Europe). Planka.nu in particular laments the superiority of the car in
what it calls "the current traffic hierarchy." "The pure act of putting oneself behind the wheel seems, for almost everyone, to lead to egotistic behavior," the group writes in one online manifesto. "We are confident that one is not born a motorist, but rather becomes one."
These fare-dodging collectives' egalitarian dream happens
to align with some hopes of U.S. policy makers. There's an intuitive,
consequentialist argument that making public transit free would get
drivers off the road and reduce greenhouse-gas emissions. In the U.S.,
where government subsidies cover between 57 and 89 percent of operating costs for buses and 29 to 89 percent of those for rail, many public-transit systems are quite affordable, costing in most cases less than $2, on average.
If it might make transit more accessible to the masses and in the
process reduce traffic and greenhouse-gas emissions, why not go all the
way and make transportation free?
The earliest urban experiment in free public transit took
place in Rome in the early 1970s. The city, plagued by unbearable
traffic congestion, tried making its public buses free. At first, many
passengers were confused: "There must be a trick," a 62-year-old Roman
carpenter told The New York Times as he boarded one bus.
Then riders grew irritable. One "woman commuter" predicted that "swarms
of kids and mixed-up people will ride around all day just because it
doesn't cost anything." Romans couldn't be bothered to ditch their
cars—the buses were only half-full during the mid-day rush hour, "when
hundreds of thousands battle their way home for a plate of spaghetti."
Six months after the failed, costly experiment, a cash-strapped Rome reinstated its fare system.
Three similar experiments in the U.S.—in Denver, Colorado,
and Trenton, New Jersey, in the late 70s, and in Austin, Texas, around
1990—also proved unfruitful and shaped the way American policy makers viewed the question of free public transit. All three were attempts to
coax commuters out of their cars and onto subway platforms and buses.
While they succeeded in increasing ridership, the new riders they
brought in were people who were already walking or biking to work. For
that reason, they were seen as failures.
A 2002 report
released by the National Center for Transportation Research indicated
that the lack of fares attracted hordes of young people, who brought
with them a culture of vandalism, graffiti, and bad behavior—which all
necessitated costly maintenance. The lure of "free," the report implied,
attracted the "wrong" crowd—the "right" crowd, of course, being
wealthier people with cars, who aren't very sensitive to price changes.
The NCTR report concluded that eliminating fares "might be successful
for small transit systems in fairly homogenous communities, it is nearly
certain that fare-free implementation would not be appropriate for
larger transit systems."
Another report
followed up 10 years later, revisiting the idea of a fare-free world.
The report reviewed the roughly 40 American cities and towns with free
transit systems. Most of the three dozen communities had been greatly
successful in increasing ridership—the number of riders shot up 20 to 60
percent "in a matter of months." But these successes were only to be
found in communities with transit needs different from those of the
biggest cities; almost all of the areas studied were either small cities
with few riders, resort communities with populations that "swell
inordinately during tourist seasons," and college towns. In other words,
slashing fares to zero is something that likely wouldn't work in big
cities.
Despite that, one big city has tried. In January 2013,
Tallinn, the capital city of Estonia, announced that it was making
public transit free to all of its citizens. A study released a year later
revealed that the move only increased demand by 1.2 percent—though it
did inspire Estonians that year to register as Tallinnian citizens at three times the normal rate.
The authors of the Tallinn study reached the same conclusion as the
NCTR: Free subway rides entice people who would otherwise walk, not
people who would otherwise drive.
What makes more sense than implementing free transit on a
grand scale is deploying it as a specialized tool. By the summer of
2013, officials in Singapore, for example, noticed that the city's
subways were getting unsustainably crowded during peak hours, between
8:15 and 9:15 in the morning. In response, the city comped rides for anyone who got off the train in a city center before 7:45.
The shift made a significant difference. Before the rule change,
peak-hours riders outnumbered off-peak riders about three to one; after,
that ratio was closer to two to one.
Getting people less frustrated with the concept of paying
for public transportation, though, might just be a matter of telling
them about its operating costs. Public transit is wildly expensive, but
also, as noted above, heavily subsidized. A 2014 study in Transportation Research
found that simply telling people just how heavily subsidized their
subways and buses were made them willing to pay more money to ride.
(Perhaps the recent price hike in New York's public-transit system would have gone over more smoothly had the system's subsidies also been publicized.)
Perhaps the cost of public transportation shouldn't be
looked at from an angle of reducing traffic and emissions. Sure, that's a
noble question, but those turnstile-hopping Swedes might have a point.
Maybe free public transit should be thought of not as a behavioral
instrument, but as a right; poorer citizens have just as much of a
privilege to get around conveniently as wealthier ones. If the debate
shifted from means-to-an-end thinking to pure egalitarianism, the hope
of free public transit might actually be realized. Until then, there's
always Planka.nu.